Economics and the Environment – Oceans and the Tragedy of the Commons

The tragedy of the commons is a dilemma in which common resources are abused because they are available to everyone, and in the absence of regulations, people will take as much as they can for themselves with little regard for the well being of the commons or their peers. Without property rights, there is not enough incentive for the commons to be preserved, and they will be depleted and destroyed. It is easy to see how this concept applies to the environment, though it is used across a very wide range of disciplines. The term was originally coined by British economist William Forster Lloyd in 1833 in an essay where he used the example of cattle grazing in the British Isles. The concept gained more exposure when Ecologist Garrett Harden wrote an article about the overuse of natural resources of all kinds in 1968, citing the tragedy of the commons as the reason why. Today, one of the biggest places we see the tragedy of the commons embodied is our oceans. Obviously, no one country can claim ownership of the oceans, and as a result it gets abused by way of overfishing and pollution which serves to damage fish populations further.

Fish populations have been dwindling rapidly over the past half a century. For example, the Atlantic bluefin tuna population is down nearly 90 percent since the 1970s as a result of overfishing (marbef). These fish are very worth an awful lot of money, since they can grow to weigh over 500 kilograms and there is no substitute for tuna in sushi. These fish take about eight years to mature, and the massive demand for their meat led to the reckless capture of juvenile fish, meaning there are not nearly enough mature fish left. While there is now a moratorium on catching juvenile Atlantic bluefin, illegal fishing still harms their numbers and is very difficult to police.

Tuna are not the only fish experiencing this problem, but just one example. Most species across the globe have been affected by overfishing, and all sorts of measures have been put in place to try to combat this issue with varying degrees of success. The U.S. and Canada had been trying to regulate fishing of Pacific halibut since the early 1920’s, and found that limiting the amount of vessels allowed to fish halibut and shortening the fishing season from 65 to 14 days yielded catastrophic results throughout the 1980’s. Halibut yields plummeted, leading the Canadian Department of Fisheries to combat the tragedy of the commons just how Lloyd originally suggested; by giving individual property rights to fishermen.

Individual Vessel Quotas, or IVQs were created, giving each fishing vessel rights to a certain percentage of the total allowable catch. The fishing season for halibut is now 245 days, alleviating the pressures that the short season put on fishermen, their equipment, and the ecosystem. Smaller, less efficient fishing operations have had their share bought out by those fishing vessels that operate more efficiently, leading to much safer conditions for fishermen and better equipment which is less likely to break and harm ecosystems as it sits in the ocean and disrupts halibut populations. Additionally, consumers now have fresher fish available to them, since less of the catch has to be frozen, which also benefits the fishermen as fresh fish is more valuable.

While this system is not perfect, it is an important proof that applying economic concepts to common environmental resources is an avenue worth exploring in the fight to preserve the planet. People simply do not respect resources they do not own or have a stake in, so privatizing wherever possible gives them a reason to care for their piece. Think about that one relative you have who refuses to accept climate change as a reality at every family gathering. Most of us know someone like this, and even where facts don’t work, money always talks. While your Ford F-350 driving uncle might not switch from incandescent to fluorescent light bulbs in his home to save the planet, he probably would take it into consideration if he realized it saved him money. The same concept applies in industries that rely on the environment. We have to make changes which benefit the industry as well as the planet, and many will be unwilling to compromise profits unless something is in it for them. Privatization solves this problem.

Sources:

https://www.perc.org/2001/03/01/fisheries-are-classic-example-of-the-tragedy-of-the-commons/

http://www.marbef.org/wiki/The_Tragedy_of_the_Commons_-_The_Tuna_Example

Lloyd, William Forster (1833). Two lectures on the checks to population. England: Oxford University. Retrieved 2016-03-13.

Hardin, G (1968). “The Tragedy of the Commons”(PDF). Science. 162 (3859): 1243–1248. doi:10.1126/science.162.3859.1243PMID 5699198.

Economics and the Environment – Employment

Those who deny the importance of transitioning to clean energy have a laundry list of reasons why things should stay the way they are. One that I hear often is that transitioning from fossil fuels to renewable energy will leave lots of people out of work, particularly those employed by the coal and oil industries. A departure from fossil fuels will leave skilled workers structurally unemployed and possibly unable to get back on their feet. When we examine the facts, it becomes abundantly clear that this is not nearly the issue that some media outlets make it out to be. Solar alone employs 43% of individuals in the power generation field, and jobs in solar continue to grow at 12 times the rate of the rest of the US economy, while jobs in coal, oil and gas have been on a steady decline since 2012.

Sure, just because renewable energy shows more promise than nonrenewable doesn’t mean we should leave those employed by the nonrenewable sector in the lurch. For the answers to this dilemma, we have to look at European nations, many of which are approaching carbon neutrality much faster than the United States. Adriaan Kamp, a Dutchman who put in 17 years at Shell now runs a clean energy consultancy is quoted as saying, “Managing a wind farm or solar project is nothing a good oil and gas man who has built or organised facilities cannot manage,” (Spectrum). This is an important thing to consider. With minimal reorientation, it seems that the skills one uses in non renewables carry over well into the renewable energy sector, so it is actually in the best interest of those working in oil and gas sector to begin to plan a transition into wind or solar. If those with experience in fossil fuels began to move to the renewable sector, particularly executives like Kamp and those with experience supervising and running fossil fuel projects, it could start a very promising trend.

There are a number of organizations in Europe which specialize in training and retraining individuals to work in the renewable energy sector, but they are still somewhat niche and not nearly as far reaching as they need to be to support the demand of the industry. Companies like Siemens, for example, have instituted a two year training program which equips graduates for work in the wind sector. If other private sector energy giants did something similar, there would no doubt be a sharp increase in skilled workers for the renewable sector. It is worth noting as well that in the US alone, 2.3 million are employed by energy transmission, storage, and distribution (New York Times). These workers would be largely unaffected by a transition to renewable energy, so there is minimal harm done to the greatest share of energy related jobs.

So the demand for fossil fuel workers in the renewable sector is there; that is not the problem. The issue rather is the slow rate at which bureaucracies worldwide are adapting to this change. The industry is hesitant to throw resources at programs to create the skills it needs to progress because government bodies remain indecisive on policy towards renewable energy as it grows faster than bills can be passed. As long as Conservatives are on the bankroll of the fossil fuel industry, it will be hard to budge certain political organizations on the issue. This issue will hopefully become lessened as the sector continues to grow, and the renewable energy industry can make more attractive offers. It is sad that politicians have to be bought to save the planet, but it is a reality that cannot be ignored and an avenue that should certainly be explored. If conservative politicians can convince their voter base that renewable energy is a solution rather than a threat to their livelihood, we will see a much greater degree of efficiency in updating policy in a world which is trending rapidly away from fossil fuels.

In the battle between renewable and non renewable energy, it is clear that renewable energy will have to emerge victorious. The facts are staggering against fossil fuels, but the bottom line is that progress in the United States in particular is not being made quickly enough, with our backing out of the Paris agreement and European countries making much greater progress towards carbon neutrality. We’ve reached the point where it now has to be out with the old and in with the new, and all parties need to start realizing that the future of energy jobs lies completely in renewables.

https://spectrum.ieee.org/energywise/energy/renewables/for-us-jobs-creation-renewables-are-a-better-bet-than-coal

http://fortune.com/2017/01/27/solar-wind-renewable-jobs/

https://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2017/04/25/climate/todays-energy-jobs-are-in-solar-not-coal.html

https://www.nrdc.org/experts/lara-ettenson/us-clean-energy-jobs-surpass-fossil-fuel-employment